Volume 16 Number 23 Produced: Mon Oct 31 8:25:21 1994 Subjects Discussed In This Issue: Ona'ah, Responses and Explanations [Seth Weissman] ---------------------------------------------------------------------- From: <SWeissman_at_BC-Faculty@...> (Seth Weissman) Date: Tue, 11 Oct 94 14:31:11 EDT Subject: Ona'ah, Responses and Explanations This is the third part of my answer to the responses to my questions. Jeff Mandin quoted Bava Metzia 61a's comparison of interest and onaah. The gemara compares these prohibitions with robbery and determines that specific prohibitions for all three are necessary because no one can be derived from any one or two of the others. This implies that the three are distinct laws. My B case (Shimon underpaying Miriam for her ring but telling her how much it is worth) is not dealt with in the mishna, but is found in the gemara in the 4th perek of Bava Metzia, as well as in the Shulchan Arukh. Jeff then quotes the vort of R. Chaim on BM 61a. R. Chaim views the overcharged amount as equivalent to stealing. To view the overcharged amount as stealing, how must we understand ona'ah? If I buy something worth $100, and not knowing its true value, pay $200, then I am paying the seller $100 for the object (I have given the seller $100 in consideration for the object which is worth $100), and a second $100 which is the overpayment. What interpretation or understanding of transactions and sales leads us to view this extra $100 as stolen? First, lets explore another way of understanding transactions. When I buy something, and overpay for it, I am saying that the object is worth (to me) the amount that I paid for it. Forgetting about purchases for the purpose of speculation and investment, when I buy something for my own use, I will never pay more for it than the value of its use to me. For example, if the pleasure I get from a drink of water is worth $1.00, I would not pay more than a dollar for a glass of water. (In the desert, the value of a glass of water is higher than it is near a well, but I would never pay more than the new value of the water, whatever that might be.) So, given that the plaintiff freely (and not under duress) agreed to pay a high price, one approach might be that the extra $100 is not stolen. Ona'ah is a new issur, unrelated to theft, and analogous to the modern concept of insider trading. There are indications that while chazzal didn't entirely buy this interpretation, they didn't reject it entirely. For example, the 1/6 border for ona'ah is not found in either robbery or burglary law. There are other ways to view the 1/6 (i.e.; a risk-sharing scheme, analogous to insurance deductibles, or as a mechanism for price limits, but these are side points right now), but the fact that within 1/6, it isn't remediable distinguishes ona'ah from theft. For now, though, let's return to theft. Well, before we start exploring the relationship between ona'ah and theft, let us be precise in our use of terminology. By stealing, we can either mean armed theft (robbery or gezala), or covert theft (burglary or genava). Common law and Jewish law distinguish between the two. The laws of mekach umemchar (sales) already deal with forced sales in Bava Basara, and the close reading of the ona'ah laws imply that ona'ah is dealing with the plaintiff's overpaying or undercharging because of a lack of information concerning the true value of the object being sold. This places ona'ah (if it can be categorized as stealing) into the realm of burglary (genava). To illustrate the last point, lets review some of the laws of ona'ah. 1. The mishna in Bava Metzia places a statute of limitations on ona'ah claims. The limit depends upon whether the plaintiff was the buyer or the seller, but in effect depends on how long the plaintiff needs to obtain information about the true value of the object. Since plaintiff buyers can more easily acquire information (being in possession of the object), sellers are granted a longer time period to register a complaint. 2. Case b of my initial posting is permissible. If the defendant informs the plaintiff at the time of the transaction that the plaintiff is being overcharged or underpaid, and includes in that admission the amount being extracted, the plaintiff's claim goes unrewarded. If the ona'ah (overpayment/underpayment) was not related to a lack of information on the part of the victim, no ona'ah claim can be made. OK, it seems that ona'ah can be compared with genava and not gezala. This then is what we should expect to find in the achronim. But, a survey of the literature reveals that R. Chaim (as well as R. Grusman) compare ona'ah to gezala. Given the similarities between ona'ah and genava, and the differences between ona'ah and gezala, their comparing the two is puzzling. One explanation for their view comes from the fifth chapter of Bava Metzia. On BM 61a, when the gemara attempts to derive interest, ona'ah, and stealing from common sources, the type of theft compared to ona'ah is gezala. This is incompatible with our understanding of ona'ah, but fits in nicely with their view of interest. So, where did a comparison of ona'ah and gezala come from? Well, the gemara was investigating the possibility that ona'ah and gezara can be derived from the same source. While they addressed the issue from a logical perspective, lets look at the basic source for ona'ah, the psukkim. In Leviticus 25, we find the source for ona'ah and one of the sources for interest. My hypothesis is that pshat in the passuk is at variance with the drash (upon which the law is based). In other words, pshat is: don't take advantage of asymmetric bargaining power (my ability to make you an offer that you cannot refuse). This is similar to gezala. The halacha comes from the drash, or non-literal interpretation of the p'sukkim. Let me note that the passuk does not say "yamuckh achichah" (when your friend or brother suffers from hardship, implying that ona'ah pertains to bargaining power) by ona'ah. I still think that this is p'shat in the passuk because the the parsha deals with the following issues: 1. the jubilee/yovel 2. the return of land with yovel 3. since land returns with the yovel, don't overcharge and don't undercharge (this is ona'ah) 4. when your brother sells his land (ki yamuckh) because of hardship, the family can help him redeem it before yovel. 5. the same as 4, dealing with cities and levite holdings in the cities designated for leviim. (ki yamuckh is repeated) 6. prohibition of interest, introduced with ki yomukh 7. redemption of slaves sold to non-jews, introduced with the phrase ki yomuckh. I think the entire parsha (in Behar, Leviticus 25) is dealing, on the p'shat level with asymmetric bargaining power. The fact that 3 (ona'ah) does not include this statement is not important because in 4, we see why the land was sold in 3. It is understood that in an agricultural society, land and farm equipment is not sold unless the seller is suffering from extreme hardship. By selling your land, you sell your livelihood and in effect your future. Without land, you cannot produce for yourself, so land, like slaves can be redeemed. Selling one's land is similar to selling one's self. If your not convinced by the above argument that ona'ah (in the psukim) is asymmetric bargaining power, then try the following: try to fit asymmetric information into the p'shat of the passuk. Skipping to the end of the perek, in number 7, we see the following law: When you redeem a slave, pay by the number of years remaining to the yovel, not more and not less. This verse parallels the verse of ona'ah (Lev. 25:14), just 25 or so verses earlier. Just what percent of slaves could not be interested in knowing how many years of service remained on ytheir contract? The same applies to land rentals. If the farmer don't know, it's not hard to find out when yovel is. Just ask the local Rabbi. If he (the ignorant, uneducated, illiterate farmer can't count and divide by 50, his Rabbi can.) So, ona'ah isn't dealing with asymmetric information, because if it were, a better case would have been used. If your still not convinced that the law doesn't follow the p'shat of the passuk, how do you explain this? The passuk's ona'ah hypothetical deals with a land sale. The mishna in Bava Metzia, chapter 4 says that ona'ah does not apply to land and salve transactions (among other things). There are various explanations for why, and Rabbi Elazar (the amorah) argues in the Yurshalmi that it does apply (in more limited circumstances). Granting all that, it's obvious that we don't learn the psukim literally. OK, so how do we learn ona'ah? Now, the halacha in the mishna, gemara, and on interpret the passukim of ona'ah out of context of the parsha as regarding asymmetric information. In other words, they interpret the p'sukim using drash, not p'shat. Why? Note that I started with the mishna. We have no sources detailing how ona'ah was applied prior to the mishna. My guess is that the Rabbis saw policies and laws preventing abuses of asymmetric information and asymmetric bargaining power as mutually exclusive. With respect to interest, in a non-commercial economy, where during bayit shayni and post destruction, most of the people were poor farmers, where most transactions were barter transactions, interest issues were not asymmetric information issues. So the prohibited interest (interpreting the psukkim literally). With regards to ona'ah, they looked at the internationalization of the Judean economy (under the Hasmonean dynasty, trade expanded dramatically with the rebuilding of the post of Yafo, and later, under Roman occupation, with the building of Cesearia, and the Roman road network. The universally accepted Roman currency helped commerce as well.) This increased the information problems as poor farmers didn't know the value of goods purchased from anonymous merchants at the biweekly markets. In these markets, asymmetric information was a major problem. Bargaining power problems may have been less of a concern by nature of the mobility of the merchants. They needed to sell their stuff because transportation costs were high, produce was perishable, and so on. The relative bargaining power of the rich merchant may not have exceeded the farmer by that much. Within the farming communities, bargaining power problems were not as severe as the information problems between the communities and the merchants. Within the farming communities, social forces were stronger. The personal nature of village life and barter economies may have prevented those with bargaining power from advantaging from it. Social pressure reduced the inefficiency producing effects of bargaining power asymmetry. In short, the economic institutions were such that the efficiency losses from asymmetric information exceeded those from asymmetric bargaining power. If the respective solutions to the two problems were mutually exclusive, efficiency dictated solving the information problem instead of the bargaining power problem. Evidence that the two are mutually exclusive can be found from the fact that option 4 is permitted. Complete revelation of information permits overcharging, and only parties with relatively, very weak bargaining positions will agree to overpay by a large amount (more than 1/6), or accept an underpayment of more than 1/6. See Bava Metzia 4, the Rambam, and the Shulcan Oruch. OK, that's a relatively long answer, but the question is a deep one. So, let's sum up: 1. The halacha of ona'ah refers to information (meaning that conceptually, if ona'ah can be compared with theft, it can only be compared with burglary, not robbery). 2. The achromim compare ona'ah to robbery. This comes from the gemara, but leaves unexplained where the gemara got it. 3. The pshat of the psukkim dealing with onaah relate to bargaining power problems, analogous to robbery, not burglary. This explains why the gemara asks is onaah can be learned from robbery or vice versa. 4. Historical analysis demonstrates that social and economic conditions led to a situation where information problems were worse than bargaining problems. 5. The Rabbis responded to the pressure of the institutional structure of their society and developed and implemented policies to respond to the problems of their day. Number 5 opens the question of how could this have happened within a halachic system. Well, hefker bet din hefker allows bet din freedom in monetary and economic issues that is unmatched anywhere within halachah. How this fits into the understanding of the halachich economic system as a utopian/optimal set of economic policies is clear. Shabbat and kosher, for example, exists as absolute laws. These laws do, however affect the economy. Kosher restrictions lower the profitability of lobster fishing, and shabbat raises worker morale. That's not the purpose of shabbat and kosher, but no one can deny that these are some of the economic consequences of these halachot. These laws, as well as social, cultural, and political phenomenon fall under the category of economic institutions. OK, now, economic policies only make sense in a given framework, so if the economic institutions are different, the policy recommendations would be different. For example, during a recession, cuts in the money supply growth rate (exacerbating the recession's effects) might be a very bad idea. But, in an expansionary period, often, cutting the money supply growth rate is the appropriate policy. So, the concept of hefker bet din hefker affords bet din complete freedom in setting economic policy. Why? Precisely because there is no optimal set of policies that deal with every situation. The world keeps changing, technology advances, and economic policies must be flexible in response to the changing conditions that they must correct for. I must admit that there is no evidence that the law of ona'ah was different before the Roman occupation (pre-mishna). We have no mention of ona'ah until that time. So, intellectual honesty forces me to categorize my above argument as speculation. I do not argue that the law of ona'ah changed; only that market conditions that ona'ah responds to had changed. Under the new market conditions the law of ona'ah (as we understand it) makes economic sense, under the prior set of economic conditions, it would have made no sense. Additionally, I defend my hypothesis by pointing to the difference between the p'shat of ona'ah and the drash of ona'ah, and the fact that within a halachic framework, the rabbis had the freedom of action to choose which interpretation of ona'ah best responded to the pressures of their times. ----------------------------------------------------------------------
End of Volume 16 Issue 23